[i] Founding Editor, No Record Press.
[ii] See Livable Communities, Transit Oriented Development, and Incorporating Green Building Practices into Federal Housing and Transportation Policy: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Transportation, Housing and Urban Development, and Related Agencies, H. Comm. on Appropriations, 110th Cong. (2008) (testimony of Sec. Shaun Donovan, U.S. Dep’t of Housing & Urban Dev.), available at http://www.hud.gov/offices/cir/test090318.cfm; Transp. for Am., Transportation and Social Equity: Opportunity Follows Mobility 3 (undated), available at http://t4america.org/policybriefs/t4_policybrief_equity.pdf (transportation costs for low-income residents nationwide are more than thirty percent of income); Brookings Inst., Commuting to Opportunity: The Working Poor and Commuting in the United States 4 (2008) (households earning between $20,000 and $49,999 spend at or above thirty percent of disposable income on transportation costs).
[iii] See Terra McKinnish et al., Who Gentrifies Low-Income Neighborhoods?, 66 J. Urb. Econ. (forthcoming 2009) (citation omitted), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w14036.pdf). While McKinnish et al. take pains to show that gentrification can have benefits to minority groups, they concede that members of those groups who lack a high school education may exit gentrifying neighborhoods at a disproportionate rate. “A black high school dropout [is] more likely than average to move into a non-gentrifying low-income neighborhood than a gentrifying low-income neighborhood.” Id. at 20.
[iv] “Usage of alternative modes of transportation drastically increases for population densities over 10,000 people per square mile, while private vehicle utilization drops. . . .” Catherine L. Ross & Anne E. Dunning, Land Use Transportation Interaction: An Examination of the 1995 NPTS Data 16 (1995) available at http://nhts.ornl.gov/1995/Doc/landuse3.pdf. In 2000, forty-two cities in the United States had population densities over 10,000. Notably, of the fifty largest cities in the United States, only seven had densities of 10,000 or more. Seven out of the ten largest cities in America fell under the threshold: Los Angeles (7876), Houston (3372), San Antonio (2708), Phoenix (2782), San Diego (3772), Dallas (3470), and Detroit (6855). See U.S. Census: U.S. Municipalities over 50,000: Ranked by 2000 Population, Demographia.com, http://www.demographia.com/db-uscity98.htm (last visited Oct. 17, 2009). Of these seven cities, only two—Los Angeles and Detroit—had a population of over 1 million in 1950 (out of the twelve American cities with a population of over 1 million in 1950). See id. However, insofar as these two urban “outliers” may have resembled “traditional” cities around 1950, they have subsequently undergone drastically different demographic shifts. First, the urban core of Detroit dropped from over 1.8 million to little over 900,000 between 1950 and 2000. See United States: Urbanized Areas and Core Cities: 1950 to 2000, Demographia.com, http://www.demographia.com/db-uscity98.htm (last visited Jan. 12, 2010). Second, between 1970 and 2000 Los Angeles’ population grew by forty-five 45 percent while its area grew by 300 percent. See Andres Duany et al., Suburban Nation: The Rise of Sprawl and the Decline of the American Dream 12 n.1 (2000) (citation omitted). While admitting that there is “substantial rural poverty,” one study points out that nearly twenty percent of the American urban population is poor, compared with less than eight percent of the rural population. See Edward L. Glaeser et al., Why Do the Poor Live in Cities? The Role of Public Transportation, 63 J. Urb. Econ. 1, 1–2 (2008) (citations omitted). For a description of the disparate cost and travel times between public and private transportation in urban areas, see id. at 12–16.
[v] See Duany, supra note iv, at 22–31. Planners’ choice to eschew serious consideration of sidewalk design was aesthetic. “The street wears us out. It is altogether disgusting. Why, then, does it still exist?” Id. at 64 (quoting Le Corbusier, The City of Tomorrow and Its Planning 129 (1929). The perils of life in the suburbs are now being felt by the victims of the current economic recession, who are forced to turn to public transportation after no longer being able to afford the cost of repairing their automobiles. See Julie Bosman, Scattered in Suburbs, and in Need, N.Y. Times, Oct. 4, 2009, at MB1, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/04/nyregion/04middle.html.
[vi] In 2003, a study of Canadian insurance schemes (also set at the province level) found that provinces which mandated carrying government-issued insurance were less expensive than those provinces that mandated insurance but left the market entirely in the hands of private companies. See Consumers’ Ass’n of Can., Review of Automobile Insurance Rates 5 (2003), available at http://consumer.ca/pdfs/030910_report.pdf. Poor investments by insurance companies lead to reduced assets, for which insurers compensate by raising premiums; the “administrative costs” of No-Fault insurance are largely illusory. See Harvey Rosenfeld, Auto Insurance: Crisis and Reform, 29 U. Mem. L. Rev. 69, 75–81 (1998)
[vii] See Rosenfeld, supra note vi, at 73–83. Personal responsibility insurance schemes have been adopted by thirty-six states. See Found. for Taxpayer & Consumer Rights, The Cost of No-Fault Auto Insurance 1–4 (2005), available at http://www.consumerwatchdog.org/documents/1812.pdf. Such schemes have a long history. See Richard M. Nixon, The Changing Rules of Liability in Automobile Accident Litigation, 3 Law & Contemp. Probs. 476, 476–80 n.6 (1936) (describing early common-law interpretations of how tort liability attached to drivers of automobiles).
[viii] See Rosenfeld, supra note vi, at 96–97.
[ix] See id. Moreover, personal damage recoveries—in the form of medical expenses—are typically larger than property damages when both arise simultaneously in an accident setting, therefore limiting even further the possibility that an indigent driver will be able to access the court system. See id. Nevertheless, courts typically uphold such schemes as constitutionally valid. See, e.g., Del Rio v. Crake, 87 Haw. 297, 955 P.2d 90, 99–100 (1998) (upholding statutory restrictions on tort thresholds under No-Fault); Pinnick v. Cleary, 360 Mass. 1, 31–32, 271 N.E.2d 592, 611 (1971) (No-Fault insurance scheme does not violate federal due process or equal protection protections); State v. Cuypers, 559 N.W.2d 435, 437 (Minn. Ct. App. 1997) (mandating No-Fault insurance does not violate constitutional right to interstate or intrastate travel); Rybeck v. Rybeck, 141 N.J. Super. 481, 493, (1976) (No-Fault statute meant to adequately compensate traffic accident victims did not violate due process).
[x] See Rosenfeld, supra note vi, at 87–90; Carinsurance.com Premium Index—National Average, Carinsurance.com, http://www.carinsurance.com/Premium-Index.aspx (last visited Jan. 12, 2010). A list of average premiums by state is also available from this site. Moreover, between 1998 and 2002, premiums rose ninety-two percent faster in No-Fault states than in personal responsibility states. See Found. for Taxpayer and Consumer Rights, supra note vii, at 1.
[xi] See Rosenfeld, supra note vi, at 87–90.
[xii] See R.S.O. 1990, ch.25; R.S.Q., ch.A-25; R.S.N.B., ch.1-12; R.S.P.E.I., ch.I-4; R.S.N.S., c.231; R.S.B.C., ch.231; R.S.A. ch.M-23; R.S.M., ch.140; S.S., ch.A-35. See generally Consumers’ Ass’n of Can., Review of Automobile Insurance Rates (2003), available at http://consumer.ca/pdfs/030910_report.pdf (arguing that free-market competition will offer consumer choice and lower prices).
[xiii] See Insurance Corporation Enabling Act, R.S.B.C., ch.228; R.S.B.C., ch.231; R.S.B.C., ch.318; Consumers’ Ass’n of Can., supra note xii, at 11.
[xiv] See Consumers’ Ass’n of Can., supra note xii, at 12, 27; Statistics Canada, Population of Census Metropolitan Areas (2006 Census boundaries), available at http://www40.statcan.ca/l01/cst01/demo05a-eng.htm.
[xv] See Bernard Simon, Anger Over Car Insurance Rates in Canada, N.Y. Times, Aug. 14, 2003, at W1, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2003/08/14/business/anger-over-car-insurance-rates-in-canada.html?pagewanted=1. Pro-private insurance trade organizations emphasize the fact that all insurance schemes, public or private, operate within a strict regulatory framework. See Insurance Bureau of Canada, Car Insurance where You Live, http://www.ibc.ca/en/Car_Insurance/Car_Insurance_Where_You_Live.asp (last visited Jan. 13, 2010). See generally Consumers’ Ass’n of Can., supra note xii (describing the processes by which insurance rates are increased).